Food
security is a very sensitive issue. India believes that trade liberalization in
agriculture has lead to a rise in process, switching of farmers from cereal crops
to cash crops leading to food shortage on macroeconomic level. Uruguay
Round produced first Memorandum in the agricultural sector which was a
significant step towards a fair competition and less distorted sector.
Agriculture will always remain a key issue in WTO. Under the GATT Agreement on
Agriculture was subjected to Soft discipline as compared to Industrial
products. The EU had implemented huge subsidies to protect the interest of its
own farmers and it has also depressed the food prices globally.
In
developing countries agriculture is not only of great economic relevance but
also, a social and political concern in India and this issue needs to be
addressed up in the ongoing negotiations on agriculture. India is one of the
developing countries where the factors discussed above are applicable and thus
the need of the hour is to negotiate on agriculture and discuss this matter
before other issues which developed countries want to negotiate. The FAO
defines Food security as the access and availability of food to people physically as well as economically,
available at all the times to them so as to live an active, healthy life
without having any risk to loss of such access and food is directly connected
with the livelihood of people in developing countries. The developing countries
are self-sufficient in producing their food requirements to satisfy their
population in spite of the constraints they have been facing by the developed
countries like USA, EU.
Agreement on Agriculture and Food Security
Issue 1: Whether Article 3.3 of the Agreement on agriculture is consistent with footnote 1 or not.
In
the EC sugar subsidies case the primary issue for consideration was whether Article 3.3 of the Agreement on agriculture
is consistent with footnote 1 or not.
The court was of the view that the intention of the drafter was to mention ‘budgetary
outlays’ and quantities together as both section 9.2(b)(iii) and 9(b)(iv) use
those words. Based on the same logic the European Communities argued that the
use of the word ‘and’ in both the section only denotes the existence of the
commitment but the member countries are not obliged to schedule it.[1]
However, this plea was rejected by the Court. The court observed that in order
to interpret both section 9.1 and 3.3, the requirement is that export subsidies
are to be expressed in terms of both budgetary outlays and quantities in
pursuant of fulfilment of the ‘long-term objective’ of the WTO which is to
provide for ‘substantial progressive reduction in agricultural support and
protection’. Thus, the fourth paragraph expresses that commitment of WTO is to
achieve binding commitment’ in export commitment. If an export subsidy is
allowed to specify only one commitment which the member chooses it would weaken
the disciples of export subsidy.
Now,
the second argument by the European communities was with regard to the
modalities paper which was referred to in two ways. Firstly, the two
commitments budgetary outlays and quantities are obligated to be scheduled but
these obligations were not carried over in the agreement on agriculture. The
European Communities does not contend that ACP/India equivalent sugar is an
incorporated product, but it was further agreed that to answer the legal
question whether there is an obligation to mention the words budgetary outlays
and quantities together in the agreement on agriculture, the treatment of
incorporated products need to be considered.[2]
The EC, however, fails to identify any provision of the modalities paper
providing any provision to schedule non-incorporated products like sugar in
terms of only budgetary outlays or quantities.
Therefore,
it was held that 3.3 requires a member to schedule both budgetary outlays and
quantities and since footnote 1 does not contain a budgetary outlay commitment
in respect to export subsidies provided to ACP/India, it is inconsistent with
article 3.3 of the agreement on agriculture.
Issue 2: whether article 9.1 is inconsistent with footnote 1 or not.
Issue 2: whether article 9.1 is inconsistent with footnote 1 or not.
The
2nd issue before the Court for consideration was whether article 9.1
is inconsistent with footnote 1 or not.
It
was argued by the European communities was that the purpose of 9.1 was to
define the scope of the subsidies which are listed under the commitment level.
Further, it was argued that Article 9.2(iv) does not specifically say that
budgetary outlay and quantity should be reduced by the coefficients mentioned
in the provision. The Court observed that as per the chapeau clause, article
9.1 the subsidies that are listed under the article are subject to reduction
commitments. Therefore, sugar subsidies are subject to reduction
commitments. The EC argued that they have fulfilled the obligation of reducing
commitment level. But the Court found no evidence to support that the European
communities have reached the commitment level both in terms of ‘budgetary
outlays’ and ‘quantitates. Hence, Article 9.1 was held to be inconsistence with
footnote 1. The Court was of the view that as per the requirement of Article
3.1, the member is required to limit its subsidization to budgetary outlay and
quantity reduction commitment as specified in the member’s schedule.
Issue 3: whether claimed commitment in Footnote 1 "limiting" subsidization of exports of sugar can prevail over the provisions of the Agreement on Agriculture, despite such a commitment being inconsistent with Articles 3.3 and 9.1 of the Agreement on Agriculture.
Issue 3: whether claimed commitment in Footnote 1 "limiting" subsidization of exports of sugar can prevail over the provisions of the Agreement on Agriculture, despite such a commitment being inconsistent with Articles 3.3 and 9.1 of the Agreement on Agriculture.
With
regard to this issue, it was submitted by the EC that footnote 1 is
inconsistent with agreement on agriculture as there is no hierarchy between
export subsidy commitment in a member schedule and agreement on agriculture.[3] The
Court, however, rejected this plea relying on the language used in article 8 of
the agreement that members can only provide subsidies when they are in
conformity with the agreement on agriculture. Footnote 1, being part of the European Communities'
Schedule is an integral part of the GATT 1994 by virtue of Article 3.1 of
the Agreement on Agriculture.
Therefore, pursuant to Article 21 of the Agreement on Agriculture, the provisions of the
Agreement on Agriculture prevail over
Footnote 1.[4]
Therefore, it was found, Footnote 1 is inconsistent
with Article 9.1 of the Agreement on Agriculture because of exports of ACP/India
equivalent sugar is not subject to reduction commitments. As Footnote 1
is inconsistent with the provisions of Articles 3.3 and 9.1, it follows that
Footnote 1 is also inconsistent with Article 8 of the Agreement. But Court
said that footnote 1 had no effect of modifying the commitment level of the
European countries as set out in the schedule.
The next issue which arose before the Court was issue
of payment. The panel examines 2 types of payment- the first one payment on export
received by the C sugar producers[5] by
governmental action through the sale of C beet below the cost of production and second
type of payment by government action in transfer of financial resources through
cross-subsidization. According to the panel both the incomes come within the
purview of Article 9 (1)(c), therefore a part of 9(1).
Issue 4: whether the sales of C beet involve export subsidies or not
Issue 4: whether the sales of C beet involve export subsidies or not
Regarding
the issue of whether the sales of C beet involve export subsidies, the panel made
3 observations- first, that
sales of C beet involved "payments", because C beet was being sold at
prices below its average total cost of production[6];
secondly, that these payments were "on the export"[7];
and, thirdly, that these "payments" were "financed by virtue of governmental action".[8] The European Communities does not appeal the
first and second of these Panel findings.
Rather, the European Communities appeals the third Panel finding, that
is, that "payments" in the form of sales of C beet are "financed
by virtue of governmental action". The
panel found that every aspect of domestic beet and sugar supply and management
is controlled by the European Countries.
In particular, the price and supply of A and B beet are fixed with a
view to ensuring a stable and adequate income to beet growers. The governmental
action of imposing penalties on the producers that divert C sugar into domestic the market is found to be indispensable to the transfer of resources from consumer and taxpayers to sugar
producers and through them to A and B beet grower.[9]
The main issue related to Agreement on Agriculture is
that European Communities provided export subsidies for sugar in excess of its
reduction commitment levels specified in Section II, Part IV of the European
Communities’ Schedule, in violation of certain provisions of the Agreement on
Agriculture and the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures
governing export subsidies.
According to article 9.1(b), the term ‘Government action’
connotes an effective power to regulate, control or supervise individuals or
restrain their action by exercising lawful authority.[10]
However, the government mandate or other directions are not necessary.[11]
Also, ‘financed’ was interpreted as mechanical or process through payment was
made to provide financial resources. That payment must not be provided by the
government but by the private parties. The appellate body further clarified
that if there is very tighter link between government actions and finance then
only be considered as ‘financed by virtue of governmental action’. This clause
gives some leeway for government involvement but that has to be decided by case
to case basis[12].
Financing of C beet by the government
The second issue involves is that EC regime regulates the
price of A and B beet and ensure stable and adequate income by providing a
contractual framework to beet grower and sugar producers. The main problem in
this regard is growing of C beet is not ‘incidental’, but rather an ‘integral’
part of the governmental regulation of the sugar market.[13]
Since both C beet grower and C sugar producer have an incentive to supply and
produce to maintain shares in A and B market and receiving demandable price.
After analysing the issue thoroughly, the appellate body decided that there
exist tight nexus between the govt action and payment. Thus the sales of C beet
cannot take place profitably at a price below the total cost of production.[14]
Further, the appellate body overlooked the second
contention raised by the EC by applying the principle of constructive res
judicata.[15]
The EC also argued that their factors also involved which do not have any link
between govt actions and finance but failed to provide distinction between
dairy product and sugar beet production. Also, contended that there exists two
type of C beet production: Production of C beet is due to “profit reasons”[16],
and another part is by ‘other factors’ which is unintended. Considering the
entire scenario, it is quite clear that the status of farmers, their continued
cultivation of C beet would not be possible without government actions.
Cross Subsidization is payment under art 9.1(c) of agreement on agriculture?
According to the EC, Cross Subsidization is mere internal
allocation of resource by the producers. Also, argued that it does not provide
any benefit to the producers. The appellate body laid down standard for
determining ‘payment’[17]
that depended on a comparison between the price of a particular product that is
‘commercial export milk’ and an ‘objective standard or benchmark’ which
reflects the proper value of that
product to its provider.[18]
The panel applied the test of average total cost of production which was denied
by the EC saying that it does not provide new additional sources to the
producers. Contrary to it, the EC argued that there has to have two entities
for receiving and granting the resources. Appellate body analysed Art 9.1(c)
and held that ‘payment’ under this article is ‘on the export of an agricultural
product’ and ‘financed by virtue of governmental action’. The appellate body
partly agreed on the contention of EC that it requires two entities but
differed on the view that in every case, it does not require two entities. The
general economic understanding is that in a business transaction the operator
makes the decision to produce and sell the product to get in return some profit
out of that production.[19]
Therefore, it was clearly established from the C beet was sold at the cost
which was very below total cost of the production which is not possible without
the help of finance from the other sources. In appeal, they also rejected the
contention of the EC that ‘benefit’ is an important element to determine the
payment under Art 9.1(c) of Agreement of Agriculture.
Proposal on Food Security
The
objective of Agreement on Agriculture is to establish a fair and market
oriented agricultural trading system with further recalling that their
objective is to provide for substantive progressive reductions in agricultural
support and protection sustained over an agreed period of time, resulting in correcting
and preventing restrictions and distortions in world agricultural markets. Also
the Preamble to Agreement on Agriculture provides that there should be reform
programmes in an equitable way among all the members having regard to non-
trade concerns including food security and the need to protect the environment.
Article 20 of the AOA provides for continuation of the reform process by
recognizing the long term objective of substantial progressive reductions by
taking into account non – trade concerns, special and differential treatment to
developing country members and to establish a fair and market-oriented the agricultural trading system along with the other objectives of the Preamble.
Agreement
on Agriculture is essential and is very important to ensure food security and
also alleviation of poverty. In developing countries agriculture is the basis
of employment to the majority of the population and workforce, leading to a
significant contribution to GDP of the developing countries. Most of the
developing countries are engaged in subsistence land farming with a small share
of landholdings, unirrigated and heavily dependent on soil, climatic factors.
The productivity is also low which causes less participation in these countries
in International trade of agricultural commodities.
The
importance of developing countries on agriculture when compared to developed
countries is based on factors like-
- Agriculture employs over 70% of the labour force in low-income countries, 30 per cent in middle-income countries and only 4 per cent in high-income countries.[20]
- A significant contribution to GDP in developing countries.
- Agriculture is an important source of revenue generation and also a significant contributor and source of foreign exchange.
- Food consumption in developing countries as compared to developed countries contributes a large share of expenditure.
- The social and economic vulnerability of agriculture in developing countries is seen from various factors like weak market orientation, low level of commercialization of agriculture, low productivity, and high dependency on monsoons, natural calamities, poor infrastructure etc.
These
factors are thus the reasons because of which a large majority of the population is
dependent on agriculture as a major source of income and livelihoods.
Thus it is the need of the hour to protect this viable source of livelihood and
to reduce the poverty level. The imports are also many times constrained by meagre
foreign exchange resources. The rise in the prices and also fluctuations in the
International market in the world the food grain markets have created a problem
for developing countries and food entitlements of the poor if it is transmitted
to domestic economies of developing countries. It is also not desirable for
developing countries to largely depend on imported food because of inadequate
physical and institutional infrastructure in rural areas. The farmers also
suffer the problem of income entitlements due to shift in cropping patterns or
relocation because of low literacy levels, limited infrastructure.
The
income entitlements of people in developing countries are largely dependent on
agricultural production and it is threatened due to an increase in subsidized
imports. Commodities which are of great significance for the developing countries
like wheat grains, oilseeds, vegetable oils, sugar etc. are subjected to high
levels of export subsidies by the developed countries. The export subsidies in
developed countries artificially depress the international prices, and thus
lower the farm incomes of producers in importing countries, thus practising
high trade distortions due to which developing countries require a level of
tariff protection. Thus developing countries should be allowed to revise the
bound levels of their sensitive items. Reduction in tariffs by the developing
countries would be considered only after a substantial reduction in trade-distorting domestic subsidies and the elimination of export subsidies.
The
green box of WTO and its present structure shows that most of the provisions
are not used by developing nations. Input subsidies given by developing
countries for crops wherein production levels are far below the average should
be covered under the green box. Also, there is a demand to exempt developing countries from the ambit of AMS calculations.
There
is also a need to address the issues like market access, domestic support,
export subsidies to enable developing countries to take care of food security
and livelihood issues.
PROPOSALS
From the above, it can be seen that the
following measures would constitute a 'Food Security Box' for developing
countries:
1. All the provisions of Annex 2 to be continued except direct payment to
producers, decoupled income support, and Government financial participation in
income insurance and income safety-net programmes.
2. All measures taken by the developing countries for poverty alleviation, rural development, rural employment and diversification of agriculture should be exempted from any form of reduction commitments.
3. Flexibility should be given to developing countries to give support to their farmers in providing subsidies.
4. Product specific support given to farmers should be excluded from AMS calculations.
5. Negative Product-specific support to be permitted to be adjusted against positive Non-product specific support to take care of inflation and depreciation.
6. Appropriate levels of tariff bindings and rationalization should be allowed to developing countries in areas like export competition, market access.
7. Rationalization of low tariff bindings in developing countries which could not be rationalized in the earlier negotiations.
8. There should be a separate safeguard mechanism on the line of Special safeguard provisions like quantitative restrictions.
9. Developing country members should be exempt from any obligation to provide any minimum market.
10. Also “product coverage” in Annex 1 of AOA is excluded and there is a demand to include products like forest produce, rubber, etc
2. All measures taken by the developing countries for poverty alleviation, rural development, rural employment and diversification of agriculture should be exempted from any form of reduction commitments.
3. Flexibility should be given to developing countries to give support to their farmers in providing subsidies.
4. Product specific support given to farmers should be excluded from AMS calculations.
5. Negative Product-specific support to be permitted to be adjusted against positive Non-product specific support to take care of inflation and depreciation.
6. Appropriate levels of tariff bindings and rationalization should be allowed to developing countries in areas like export competition, market access.
7. Rationalization of low tariff bindings in developing countries which could not be rationalized in the earlier negotiations.
8. There should be a separate safeguard mechanism on the line of Special safeguard provisions like quantitative restrictions.
9. Developing country members should be exempt from any obligation to provide any minimum market.
10. Also “product coverage” in Annex 1 of AOA is excluded and there is a demand to include products like forest produce, rubber, etc
Conclusion
It can be seen from the above Agreement on
Agriculture that Food security is an extremely important
issue and it needs to be addressed in WTO negotiations. India is a developing
country and the farmers are heavily depended on it. If subsidiaries are not
given to the farmers of developing nations they will not be able to trade
internationally and also will not be able to survive as they are totally
dependent on agriculture as a major source of livelihood. The proposals put by
India in WTO in 2001 are still not addressed and the situation is the same even
after 14 years.
When it comes to the European Community they
should not completely do away with the subsidies to their farmers otherwise
they will become totally dependent on other countries and these other countries
may take advantage of such a situation by giving crops etc at a very high
price etc. But at the same time while exporting minimum level of standards need
to be maintained. The product should not be exported below the average cost price
of the product which may otherwise lead to prejudice to other developing
countries.
[1] European Communities'
appellant's submission, para. 139
[2] European
Communities' statement at the oral hearing
[3] European
Communities' appellant's submission, para. 156
[4] Ibid.
[5] Panel report para 7.338
[6] Panel Reports,
para. 7.270.
[7] Ibid., para. 7.279.
[8] Ibid., para. 7.292.
[9] European Communities' Appellant's Submission, para. 268.
[10] Appellate Body Report, Canada – Dairy, para. 97.
[11] Appellate Body Report, Canada – Dairy (Article 21.5 – New Zealand
and US II), paras. 127-128
[12] Appellate Body Report, Canada – Dairy (Article 21.5 – New Zealand
and US II), para. 134 (referring to
Appellate Body Report, Canada – Dairy (Article 21.5 – New Zealand and US),
para. 115)
[13] See FN 373.
[14] para 239
[15] Sales of A and B beet are ‘largely insufficient to cover all the fixed
costs of producing C beet’ was not argued before the panel.
[16] beet grower takes additional advantage by selling C beet above marginal cost.
[17] Canada – Dairy (Article 21.5 – New Zealand and US)and Canada –
Dairy (Article 21.5 – New Zealand and US
II)
[18] para 260
[19] para 266
[20] UNCTAD 1999 'Examining Trade in the Agricultural Sector, with A
View to Expanding the Agricultural Exports of the Developing Countries, and to Assisting them in
Better Understanding the Issues at Stake in the Upcoming Agricultural Negotiations', TD/B/Com.l/EM.8/2, 23
February 1999.
0 Comments